Life in a slum: opportunity or poverty trap?

Credit: periodismohumano
Credit: periodismohumano

It is estimated that at least 860 million people live in slums, a number that has been growing by six million a year from 2000 to 2010 (UN-Habitat 2012) 1. The study of slums worldwide is a very complex problem. We have no good model to study their economic performance, no systematic data and no way to test hypotheses properly. We do have, on the other hand, many surveys that collected data for different variables in a sample of slums. The present article summarizes Marx et al. (2013) 2, a study that puts together all the available information to have one of the most complete pictures so far. (I will only cite a fraction of the references, which may be consulted in this main reference.) In a work that shows how good descriptive analysis can be of scientific use, the authors shed some light on three important questions:

  1. Do migrants that move to a slum improve their lives?

  2. Are slums opportunities for social upgrading or poverty traps?

  3. Which policies are better for improving living conditions for people in the slums? In particular, are land and property titling programs beneficial?

Slums

(i) The revealed preference hypothesis

According to this basic economic principle, people from poor rural areas that moved to a slum must be better off, as they freely choose to go there. Indeed, the available studies confirm this hypothesis. Glaeser (2011) 3 provide evidence that the urban poor worldwide are on average richer and happier than their rural counterparts, and Chowdhury et al. (2009) 4 show that seasonal urban migration in Bangladesh can generate welfare improvements for families of migrants. However this does not validate per se the hypothesis of slums being launching pads for upward mobility, as the improvement may not be enough to provide a consistent upgrading of economic conditions along time.

(ii) Opportunities or poverty traps?

A first fact that becomes clear in the data is that, for many slums, living standards do not seem to be improving over time. For instance, in Kibera, Kenya, census data that measure variables like education, number of rooms per capita and the share of pit latrines, among others, suggest that living conditions have either deteriorated or at best stagnated over the 1999–2009 period, a period during which the economy as a whole grew at 3.5% annually.

Of course, this simple analysis overlooks a selection problem: households that improved their condition may no longer live in the slum, while other poor households may have migrated into it. The available evidence, overall, does not provide evidence of rapid changes in the composition of slums. In the Kibera data, respondent households have lived in the slum for 16 years on average, and incomes do not increase with the duration of residency. In the Bangladeshi settlements, income per capita correlates negatively with the total number of years that that household has spent in the slum and with the number of years since the households first left the countryside. Similarly, UN-Habitat (2003) 5 reported that 41 percent of Kolkata slum dwellers had lived in slums for over 30 years, and more than 70 percent had lived in slums for over 15 years. In a case study of Bangkok slums, 60 percent of individuals were reportedly born in the same slum.

The notion of slums being a poverty trap implies that households do not necessarily move there planning to stay, but instead get caught in a low-level equilibrium. The APHRC (2013) 6 data does speak to this: very few slum residents moved, only about 15 percent, and one-third of these stayed in slum areas.

On the causes that make slums poverty traps, the authors collect data on health, investment and policy indicators, providing a picture that is consistent with the theoretical economic models of poverty traps as described in Azariadis and Drazen (1990) 7 and reviewed empirically in López-Casanovas et al. (2005) 8, Bleakley (2010) 9, and Currie and Vogl (2013)10 . The health indicators show a very low dwelling size, very high population densities, community taps shared by dozens of families, a high percentage of toilet sits infected, and life expectancy lower and infant mortality higher than in rural and no-slum areas. In fact, a very high number of household report one member being ill in the previous month.

The investment indicators show that most slum inhabitants do not own their place and pay a high portion of their income as rent, and that simple improvements are relatively expensive. Public investment is very difficult as the interests of the slumlords, who control the land and housing markets and very often are local bureaucrats, gang members or drug dealers, are not aligned with the interests of the silent majority of slum dwellers. In addition, slums are not usually eligible pro urban planning, and their populations are undercounted. Finally, slums are subject to the Torado (1976) 11 paradox: living standards cannot be improved without generating an additional influx of rural migrants, which in turn depresses public and private investments in the existing settlements.

(iii) The land titling paradigm

The writings of De Soto (2000) 12 were influential in refocusing the slum debate towards issues of land tenure and land rights. De Soto argued that giving the poor property titles over their land would provide collateral for millions of poor urban households across the developing world. In fact, the positive relationship between tenure security and investments in land has been well documented in the empirical literature for rural settings. However, few academic studies have looked at the impact of urban titling programs on the investment decisions made by households in slums.

Marx et al. (2013) are not optimistic and provide evidence that land titling may not work as desired. Most land owners live outside the slum and seem to have no problems having their informal rights over the renters strongly enforced (Syagga et al., 2002 13). Palmer (1998) 14 pointed out how the effectiveness of land titling programs actually depended on whether they could achieve an increase in the total security that poor households enjoy. More interestingly, Durand-Lasserve et al. (2007) 15 reviewed evidence from land titling projects that may have actually decreased tenure security (because they allowed for lawfully enforced evictions) in Afghanistan, Cambodia, Egypt, India, and Rwanda.

Recommendations

Past approaches to slums tried to reduce their population with evictions and neglect. The idea was to discourage migration to the slum and encourage people to leave. By the 1970s it was clear that these measures did not work and policies for upgrading the slum took place. However, initial enthusiasm of upgrading projects began to dwindle by the late 1980s as slums continued to expand and the basic infrastructure improvements appeared unsustainable.

The experience of countries that managed to curb the growth of slums, such as Brazil or Egypt (see Figure), appear to be those where slum policy relied on a combination of instruments rather than focusing on a single one —including efforts to increase the transparency and efficiency of land markets, to improve local governance, to increase public investments massively, and to increase the supply of cheap housing (UN-Habitat 2010 16).

References

  1. UN-Habitat.2012. State of the world’s cities 2012/2013: prosperity of cities. Nairobi: United Nations Human Settlements Programme.
  2. Marx, B., Stoker T., and Suri T. 2013. The economics of slums in the developing world. Journal of Economic Perspectives 27, 187-210.
  3. Glaeser, E.2011. Triumph of the city: how our greatest invention makes us richer, smarter, greener, healthier, and happier.New York, NY: Penguin Press.
  4. Chowdhury, S., Mobarak A.M., and Bryan G.2009. Migrating away from a seasonal famine: a randomized intervention in Bangladesh. Human Development Research Paper 2009/41.
  5. UN-Habitat.2003. The challenge of slums: global report on human settlements 2003. London and Sterling, VA: Earthscan Publications.
  6. APHRC. 2013. NUHDSS (Nairobi Urban Health and Demographic Surveillance Site) dataset.
  7. Azariadis, C., and Drazen A.1990. Threshold externalities in economic development. Quarterly Journal of Economics 105, 501–26.
  8. López-Casasnovas, G., Rivera, B., and Currais, L. eds.2005. Health and economic growth: findings and policy implications.Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
  9. Bleakley, H. 2010. Health, human capital, and development. Annual Review of Economics 2, 283-310.
  10. Currie, J., and Vogl, T.2013. Early-life health and adult circumstance in developing countries. Annual Review of Economics 5, 1–36
  11. Todaro, M.P.1976. Urban job expansion, induced migration, and rising unemployment: a formulation and simplified empirical test for LDCs. Journal of Development Economics 3, 211–25.
  12. de Soto, H.2000. The mystery of capital: why capitalism triumphs in the west and fails everywhere else.Basic Books.
  13. Syagga, P., Mitullah W., and Karirah-Gitau S.2002. Nairobi situation analysis supplementary study: a rapid economic appraisal of rents in slums and informal settlements (draft). Contribution to the Preparatory Phase (January-November 2002) of the Government of Kenya & UN-HABITAT Collaborative Nairobi Slum Upgrading Initiative.
  14. Palmer, D.1998. Security, Risk and Registration. Land Use Policy 15, 83–94.
  15. Durand-Lasserve, A., Fernandes, E., Payne, G., and Rakodi, C.2007. Social and economic impacts of land titling programmes in urban and peri-urban areas: a review of the literature. Paper presented at the World Bank Urban Research Symposium, Washington DC, May 2007.
  16. UN-Habitat.2010. State of the world’s cities 2010/2011.Nairobi: United Nations Human Settlements Programme.

Written by

1 comment

  • This is wonderful. It has given me insights on issues that I am aiming to tackle in my undergraduate thesis. Your references too have opened a doorway to a clearer image on what I will need to address.

    Thank you!

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published.Required fields are marked *